You are here

Why small booms cause big busts

Jul 30,2015 - Last updated at Jul 30,2015

As bubbles go, it was not a very big one.

From 2002 to 2006, the share of the American economy devoted to residential construction rose by 1.2 percentage points of GDP above its previous trend value, before plunging as the United States entered the greatest economic crisis in nearly a century.

According to my rough calculations, the excess investment in the housing sector during this period totalled some $500 billion — by any measure a tiny fraction of the world economy at the time of the crash.

The resulting damage, however, has been enormous. The economies of Europe and North America are roughly 6 per cent smaller than we would have expected them to be had there been no crisis.

In other words, a relatively small amount of overinvestment is responsible for some $1.8 trillion in lost production every year.

Given that the gap shows no signs of closing, and accounting for expected growth rates and equity returns, I estimate that the total loss to production will eventually reach nearly $3 quadrillion.

For each dollar of overinvestment in the housing market, the world economy will have suffered $6,000 in losses. How can this be?

It is important to note that not all recessions cause so much pain. Financial blows in 1987, 1991, 1997, 1998, and 2001 (when some $4 trillion of excess investment was lost when the dot-com bubble burst) had little impact on the broader real economy.

The reason why things were different this time can be found in a recently published paper by Òscar Jordà, Moritz Schularick, and Alan M. Taylor.

Large credit booms, the authors show, can greatly worsen the damage caused by the collapse of an asset bubble.

Historically, when a recession is caused by the collapse of an asset bubble that was not fuelled by a credit boom, the economy is roughly 1-1.5 per cent below what it otherwise would have been five years after the start of the downturn.

When a credit boom is involved, however, the damage is significantly greater.

When the bubble is in equity prices, the economy performs 4 per cent below par, on average, after five years — and as much as 9 per cent below par when the bubble is in the housing market.

Given these findings, it is clear that the distress experienced since the beginning of the economic crisis is not far out of line with historical experience.

For many economists, recessions are an inevitable part of the business cycle — the bust that necessarily follows, like a hangover, from any boom.

John Maynard Keynes, however, had little time for this view.

“It seems an extraordinary imbecility that this wonderful outburst of productive energy should be the prelude to impoverishment and depression,” Keynes wrote in 1931, after the boom years of the 1920s had given way to the Great Depression.

“I find the explanation of the current business losses, of the reduction in output, and of the unemployment which necessarily ensues on this not in the high level of investment which was proceeding up to the spring of 1929, but in the subsequent cessation of this investment.”

A few years later, Keynes proposed a fix to the problem. In The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, Keynes explained how booms are created when “investments which will in fact yield, say, 2 per cent in conditions of full employment are made in the expectation of a yield of, say, 6 per cent and are valued accordingly”.

In a recession, the problem is flipped. Investments that would yield 2 per cent are “expected to yield less than nothing”.

The result is a self-fulfilling prophecy, in which widespread unemployment does indeed drive the returns of those investments below zero.

“We reach a condition where there is a shortage of houses,” Keynes wrote, “but where nevertheless no one can afford to live in the houses that there are.”

His solution was simple: “The right remedy for the trade cycle is not to be found in abolishing booms and thus keeping us permanently in a semi-slump; but in abolishing slumps and thus keeping us permanently in a quasi-boom.”

For Keynes, the underlying problem was a failure of the economy’s credit channels.

The financial reaction to the collapse of a bubble and the resulting wave of bankruptcies drives the natural rate of interest below zero, even though there are still many ways to put people productively to work.

Today, we recognise that clogged credit channels can cause an economic downturn. There are three commonly proposed responses.

The first is expansionary fiscal policies, with governments taking up the slack in the face of weak private investment. The second is a higher inflation target, giving central banks more room to respond to financial shocks.

And the third is tight restrictions on debt and leverage, especially in the housing market, in order to prevent a credit-fuelled price bubble from forming.

To these solutions, Keynes would have added a fourth, one known to us today as the “Greenspan put” — using monetary policy to validate the asset prices reached at the height of the bubble.

Unfortunately, in a world in which fiscal austerity appears to exert a mesmerising hold over politicians, and in which a 2 per cent inflation target seems set in stone, our policy options are rather limited.

And that, ultimately, is how a relatively small boom can lead to such a large bust.

 

The writer is professor of economics at the University of California at Berkeley and a research associate at the National Bureau of Economic Research. ©Project Syndicate, 2015. www.project-syndicate.org

up
4 users have voted.
PDF