You are here

Explaining inflation inertia

May 22,2019 - Last updated at May 22,2019

CAMBRIDGE — The stubbornness of inflation continues to challenge and mystify central bankers worldwide. Whether they are trying to boost price growth or rein it in, policymakers are effectively wrestling with the same problem.

Consider Japan, which has experienced deflation, a decline in the price level, in 11 of the past 20 years. Since 2016, deflationary forces appear to have receded, but inflation rates have consistently remained well below the 2 per cent target set by the Bank of Japan (BOJ), despite accommodative policies. The BOJ has maintained the policy interest rate below zero since 2016, capped long-term rates near zero and expanded the monetary base by about 250 per cent since 2013 via record purchases of Japanese government bonds. The BOJ now holds about 50 per cent of the outstanding stock of government bonds. This is no small achievement, as Japan’s government debt ratio, at 238 per cent of GDP, is the highest in the world. And yet, despite these policies, inflation expectations five years out are still anchored close to 1 per cent.

At the other end of the spectrum, there is Argentina’s ongoing inflation battle. The Central Bank of Argentina, in connection with an International Monetary Fund (IMF) programme in June 2018, promised to keep the monetary base unchanged. This has forced the policy rate to climb to almost 74 per cent. Nonetheless, the annual inflation rate has accelerated from around 26 per cent a year ago to about 55 per cent.

The pick-up in inflation largely reflects higher import prices, as the peso crashed, plummeting about 115 per cent against the US dollar during the 12 months that ended in March. But pass-through from the exchange rate to the price level is only part of the story. And an overheated economy has played no role at all. On the contrary, Argentina is grappling with a deep and lingering recession. The IMF expects GDP to shrink by 1.2 per cent this year, following a larger contraction in 2018.

And yet, despite a credit crunch and other indications of tight monetary conditions and a recent spate of price controls, inflation remains close to 40 per cent. Under President Mauricio Macri’s administration, Argentina had a short-lived spell of inflation targeting during 2016-2018. When the scheme was unveiled, the 2019 target was set at within 1.5 percentage points of 5 per cent. Credibility has been a problem.

Why have inflation expectations failed to respond to draconian changes in policies?

In 2001, 1 Argentina peso traded for $1; today, $1 costs around 44 pesos, a cumulative depreciation of over 4,000 per cent). Since 2001, the Japanese yen has appreciated about 12 per cent against the US dollar, and by almost 70 per cent since the exchange rate began floating in 1971. Any modest amount of extrapolation would attach a low weight to a near-term yen crash or to a stable peso. During times of global financial market stress, there was a flight not only to US dollars, the global reserve currency, but also to yen and swiss francs. In 2008-2009, for example, nearly all other currencies crashed.

These secular exchange-rate trends reinforce existing preferences in saving-consumption patterns and asset allocation. In the case of Japan, prior to the more recent era of negative real interest rates, they allowed savers to maintain the purchasing power of their savings. They also help to explain the strong Japanese bias toward domestic, yen-denominated assets.

As for Argentina, chronic inflation and currency depreciation have cemented a clear preference for the US dollar as a store of value. The compulsory “pesoisation” in January 2002, when existing US dollar deposits and loans in the domestic banking sector were forcibly converted to pesos, provided only a temporary and artificial reduction in the domestic use of the US dollar. Saving rates are low, and a nontrivial share of private savings is held outside the country. As Christoph Trebesch and I have highlighted, reliance on fickle foreign saving does not help with currency instability or external indebtedness.

So, what can governments do to induce turning points in stubborn inflation expectations when central banks’ policies prove insufficient to the task?

In the case of Japan, convincing the private sector that higher inflation is the path of the future requires a break from the current practice of indexing public-sector wages to the previous year’s inflation. Bold increases in public-sector wages may provide the official signal that has been lacking, with private-sector wage and price setting following suit. The very fact that such a measure would run counter to fiscal prudence in such a highly indebted country might help undermine the entrenched trend toward yen appreciation. Higher inflation has to be part of the solution to the existing overhang of public and private debt.

As for Argentina, to avoid fuelling a classic wage-price spiral, de-indexation requires significant reductions in real wages, starting with the public sector. The political difficulty of doing this, especially when the public sector is large, as it is in Argentina, is daunting at the best of times; in an election year, there is, at least as far I am aware, limited historical precedent for it. Apart from dampening inflation expectations, real wage cuts mitigate the real exchange-rate appreciation, loss of competitiveness, that often accompanies disinflation plans. For a country like Argentina, facing increasing difficulties in global capital markets, current-account deficits are a luxury.

Perhaps inflation expectations are stubbornly high, or low, because the public has learned to extrapolate from another historical trend: Governments tend to avoid making difficult choices.

 

Carmen M. Reinhart is professor of the International Financial System at Harvard University’s Kennedy School of Government. Copyright: Project Syndicate, 2019. www.project-syndicate.org

up
66 users have voted, including you.


Newsletter

Get top stories and blog posts emailed to you each day.

PDF